Economics defines a
consumer as a rational individual is keen to maximize his/her utility by making
rational choices. More often choices come in when a consumer is in exposed to
two goods, where a given amount of one substitutes the use of another one. To understand
the rationality of a consumer in such a situation, an indifference curve is
used. For instance, the curve is used to explain how a consumer makes work and
leisure related choices given differentials in the wage rate. More often, the
analysis of an indifference curve brings together the combination of two vital
concepts, the budget constraints largely referred to as budget lines and the
indifference curves (McTaggart et al., 2010).
This essay seeks to expound how this analysis can be used to come up
with an individual labor supply schedule.
An indifference curve can be defined
as a line that pinpoints possible combinations between two goods (Edgmand et
al., 2007). These combinations showcase points where a consumer is indifferent,
that is a consumer is able to derive the same level of satisfaction from any
points in the curve. The figure below explains this scenario very well.
Diagram
1
Source: (Jackson et al., 2008, pg. 233)
The
graph above is a pictorial representation of how workers are able to maximize
their revenues by balancing working hours and leisure hours. From the graph, a worker is able to realize
the same level of utility or satisfaction by either combining 6 leisure hours
with 2 working hours or relatively by opting for 3 leisure hours and 5 work
hours’ combination. That implies that the worker is equally satisfied at point
A as he is satisfied at point B. The aforementioned is possible despite the
worker utilizing more leisure hours at point A or by opting for more working
hours i.e. at point B. When a customer moves from point A to point B, it means
that he/she is willing to forego 3 hours of leisure for 3 hours of work.
In real economic world, rational individuals will their
hard earned income on quite a number of goods and services in every stage of
their life. During these developments, they will be exposed to changes in
interest rates as well as commodity prices. The interest rates are used to
measure and ascertain the cost associated with commodities being consumed in relation
to future expectations. Considering the negative externalities present in world
markets, individuals are exposed to uncertainties whereby they may or may not
realize their full utility and subsequent satisfaction. The aforementioned
implies that advanced analysis of the indifference curve is relevant to
ascertain how utility is derived. The analysis is based on two goods, income
and leisure. However, it is prudent to expect that at the equilibrium of these
two goods under analysis, the marginal rate of substitution equals the relative
prices of the pair (Taylor & Moosa, 2008).
To maximize utility in the commodity market, one needs to
have access to good amounts of income. This income is often earned as a reward
of labor, where a worker sells his/her labor power for a wage or salary. In
indifference curve analysis, a worker derives his satisfaction by allocating
them to work and leisure. Despite it not being considered a good i.e. quite a
number of people believe that it lowers satisfaction, indifference curve helps
in the determination of how people are willing to work. Workers often assert that leisure, which is
an opposite of work, generates much utility. However, that might not
necessarily be the case in reality as consumers require income to enhance their
welfare (McTaggart et al., 2010).
A normal good can be defined as a commodity whose price
is largely depended on the income of the consumer. This implies that with an
increase in the level of income, a customer will consume more of the good. On the
other hand, a reduction in the level of income will largely hamper the demand
of such a good. From the above, it is apparent that the nature of a good often
changes depending on income range. Therefore, there is a high possibility that
a good may be a normal good as well as an inferior good. On matters income, an
individual who has a low income will often forgo leisure for work. In this case
therefore, leisure may be a normal good. That is, the worker will consume an
addition leisure hour for every increased penny in his income levels. However, considering the consumer income
increases rapidly, then more leisure hours will be foregone in the process
(Edgmand et al., 2007). The graph below
explains the scenario where leisure becomes a normal good at some point.
Therefore, the ultimate question that sought to be answered here is how much
leisure hour a worker is willing to sacrifice for a unit increase in his wage.
Put simply, each individual has a fixed number of hours, often 24 hours.
Individuals have to divide these 24 hours to work and leisure. From the above,
the question can now be paraphrased to capture the autonomous levels of leisure
demanded at given wage units.
Diagram
2: Source:
(Jackson et al., 2008, pg. 237)
Given there is a relative increase in a workers income,
the cost of leisure rises, that is it becomes expensive. Therefore, individuals
are willing to increase their working hours and reduce their leisure hours. That
is, they are ready to substitute or else forego leisure for income. E3 to E1 in
the graph above depicts this scenario well. On the other hand, increase in the
wages advanced to workers leads to an increase in their income levels, this
therefore leads to a shift of the budget line together with the equilibrium to
point E2 from E1. The points E1 and E2 above are the optimum levels of consumer
satisfaction. The shift showcased in the diagram above resulted because leisure
is considered a normal good, meaning the individual is willing to increase
leisure consumption. When the aggregate effect of substitution and income is
greater than zero i.e. SE+IE>0, consumers are engaging more of their time in
work. This therefore implies that there is a rapid decrease in leisure consumption
(Stonecash et al., 2009). The aforementioned case is only possible when wages
rise.
The state of leisure often fluctuates between being an
inferior or a normal good. Leisure possesses the attributes of an inferior good
given wages are low. However, it is considered a normal good when the wages are
relatively high. Often, individuals
often seek to increase their income levels when their wage bill is low. They do
this to increase their ability to afford other consumer goods in the market. To
these persons, they prefer more work to leisure when there is a remarkable
increase in wages. However, when they have accrued more riches, leisure takes
the state of a normal good (Taylor & Moosa, 2008).
McTaggart et al. (2010) defines unemployment benefits as monetary
compensation extended to unemployed persons by either a state or an authorized body.
Unemployed persons are individuals who are willing and able to work but are yet
to secure one. To be awarded a benefit, a person has to be in government
registry. The benefits are expected to cushion these persons from the ever
rising cost of living. This implies that they not only gather for basic needs
but also act as a compensation for lost man hours in relation to a past
payment. From diagram 2 above, every individual consumer has a time constraint
of 24 hours that can be awarded to leisure or work. The 24 hours are captured
well by the X intercept. Given that a consumer invests all his hours in work,
it means that he has no time for leisure and vice versa. However, in the case
of an unemployed individual, all the hours can be utilized for leisure.
Unemployment benefits deprive individuals urge to work. This is because a
consumer is able to improve his utility by utilizing the amount offered well. It
can as well be said that an increase in consumer benefits increases his ability
to purchase a relatively high combination of market commodities. This therefore
leads to a shift in the budget line i.e. from E1 to E2 in diagram 2 above.
Despite
the relief that come with the benefits, consumers still face the wrath of living
costs. That is, although the benefits aide in the acquisition of basic needs,
it fails to guarantee a good future. This leaves consumers with an increasing
urge to earn more with their own efforts. Consumers are often in need of
diversity and given the fact that human wants are insatiable, workers will seek
to sell their efforts at relatively cheaper prices in order to attract buyers.
Having started from zero wages, these workers will seek to harness more wealth
by fully utilizing their labor power. In the long run, they will have more
income to spend and further increase in wages might fail to trigger their urge
towards additional incomes.
The labor supply schedule is a representation of how
labor reward or wage relates with the quantity supplied of labor (Hatch, 2010).
The labor supply schedule guides in the derivation of a labor supply curve, a
graph that eases the monitoring of worker decisions. For example, from the
graph, time allocated to work by a worker can be deduced quite easily. In the
contemporary business market, supply curves are often associated with
producers. However, with the labor market, the consumer is often the supplier. Labor
market decisions are often done by individuals seeking to sell their services
for wages. Therefore, a consumer economic theory is of utmost importance in the
deriving process of a supply curve.
According
to Jackson et al. (2008), economic theory enables one understand the number of
hours a worker is willing and able to invest for increased incomes. Being a
rational being, a worker is expected to be driven by the urge to improve his
standards of living by coping with the ever increasing living costs. To realize
this, he has to seek to increase his income at all costs. Increased income
therefore increases his ability to choose between various goods in the market.
However, this quest for increased income often subdues when one has accrued a
lot of wealth.
In
conclusion, it is apparent that indifference curve analysis plays a cardinal
role in understanding the rationality of consumers. From the above discussion,
it can be observed that consumers are often driven by the urge to gain most
satisfaction from the combination of goods that is his utility is of utmost
importance. In matters related to the labor market, there is a tradeoff between
hours spending on work and those utilized for leisure services. More often,
quite a number of people prefer work to leisure although the same is
irrational. This is because the need to acquire other goods in the market supersedes
leisure satisfaction. Another notable thing in the above discussion is the
variation of leisure state, i.e. being both a normal and an inferior good. For
example, a low wage will always push a consumer to work. This is because of the
urge to increase once income and be able to afford other commodities in the
market. For these workers, they are keen to inject more hours into work
especially when the wages are in the rise. This implies that leisure hours are
sacrificed. However, the same tends to change when these workers have accrued a
lot of wealth and enjoying strong financial muscle. This is the time when
leisure turns from being an inferior good to being a normal good. This is
because they are keen to enjoy more leisure than work. Therefore, at this state,
despite wage increases, labor supply is often mild.
Reference List
Edgmand,
M. R., Moomaw, R. L. & Olsen, K. W. 2007, Economics and contemporary issues, 7th edn, Thomson, South-Western.
Hatch,
J. V. 2010, Reading between the lines.
Pearson, Frenchs Forest, NSW.
Jackson,
J., McIver, R. & McConnell, C. 2008, Economic
principles, 2nd edn, McGraw-Hill, Sydney.
McTaggart,
D., Findlay, C. & Parkin, M. 2010, Economics,
6th edn. Pearson, Sydney.
Stonecash,
R., Gans, J., King, S. & Mankiw, N. G. 2009, Principles of economics, 4th edn. Thomson.
Taylor,
J. B. & Moosa, I. 2008, Economics,
4th edn. John Wiley, Brisbane.
woow expressed it in simple term
ReplyDelete